UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20580
Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Christine S. Wilson
Regarding the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking for the Non-Compete Clause Rule
Commission File No. P201200-1
January 5, 2023
Today, the Commission announced a notice of proposed rulemaking (“NPRM”) for a Non-
Compete Clause Rule. “The proposed rule would provide that it is an unfair method of
competition – and therefore a violation of Section 5 – for an employer to enter into or attempt to
enter into a non-compete clause with a worker; [or to] maintain with a worker a non-compete
clause . . .”0F
1
For the many reasons described below, on the current record, I do not support
initiating the proposed rulemaking and consequently dissent.
The proposed Non-Compete Clause Rule represents a radical departure from hundreds of years
of legal precedent that employs a fact-specific inquiry into whether a non-compete clause is
unreasonable in duration and scope, given the business justification for the restriction. The
Commission undertakes this radical departure despite what appears at this time to be a lack of
clear evidence to support the proposed rule. What little enforcement experience the agency has
with employee non-compete provisions is very recent (within the last week) and fails to
demonstrate harm to consumers and competition. Lacking enforcement experience, the
Commission turns to academic literature – but the current record shows that studies in this area
are scant, contain mixed results, and provide insufficient support for the scope of the proposed
rule. And one study illustrates clearly, in the financial services sector, the negative unintended
consequences of suspending non-compete provisions, including higher fees and broker
misconduct. The suspension of non-competes across all industry sectors in the U.S. undoubtedly
will impose a much larger raft of unintended consequences.
Setting aside the substance of the rule, the Commission’s competition rulemaking authority itself
certainly will be challenged. The NPRM is vulnerable to meritorious challenges that (1) the
Commission lacks authority to engage in “unfair methods of competition” rulemaking, (2) the
major questions doctrine addressed in West Virginia v. EPA applies, and the Commission lacks
clear Congressional authorization to undertake this initiative; and (3) assuming the agency does
possess the authority to engage in this rulemaking, it is an impermissible delegation of legislative
authority under the non-delegation doctrine, particularly because the Commission has replaced
1
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking for Non-Compete Clause Rule (“NPRM”) Part I (Jan. 5, 2023).
2
the consumer welfare standard with one of multiple goals. In short, today’s proposed rule will
lead to protracted litigation in which the Commission is unlikely to prevail.
The NPRM invites public comment on both a sweeping ban on non-competes and various
alternatives pursuant to the Administrative Procedure Act, not the Magnuson-Moss Act.
Stakeholders should note that this solicitation for public comment is likely the only opportunity
they will have to provide input not just on the proposed ban, but also on the proposed
alternatives. For this reason, I encourage all interested parties to respond fully to all parts of the
NPRM’s solicitation of public comments.
Non-Compete Clauses Merit Fact-Specific Inquiry
Based on the current record, non-compete clauses constitute an inappropriate subject for
rulemaking. The competitive effects of a non-compete agreement depend heavily on the context
of the agreement, including the business justification that prompted its adoption. But don’t take
my word for it – the need for fact-specific inquiry aligns with hundreds of years of precedent.
When assessing the legality of challenged non-compete agreements, state and federal courts (and
English courts before them) have examined the duration and scope of non-compete clauses, as
well as the asserted business justifications, to determine whether non-compete clauses are
unreasonable and therefore unenforceable.1F
2
The NPRM itself acknowledges, at least implicitly, the relevance of the circumstances
surrounding adoption of non-compete clauses. For example, the NPRM proposes an exception to
the ban on non-compete clauses for provisions associated with the sale of a business,
acknowledging that these non-compete clauses help protect the value of the business acquired by
the buyer.2F
3
Recognizing that senior executives typically negotiate many facets of their
employment agreements, the NPRM distinguishes situations in which senior executives are
subject to non-compete provisions.3F
4
And to stave off potential legal challenges, the NPRM
proposes more carefully tailored alternatives to a sweeping ban on non-compete clauses that
instead would vary by employee category.
2
See, e.g., United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 281 (6th Cir. 1898) (Taft, J.), aff’d in relevant
part, 175 U.S. 211 (1899); Mitchel v. Reynolds, 1 P. Wms. 181 (1711).
3
NPRM Part V, Section 910.3.
4
Accordingly, the Commission seeks comments on whether senior executives should be treated differently from the
proposed ban on non-compete clauses. See NPRM Parts IV.A.1.b, IV.A.1.c. In a similar vein, recent consent
agreements issued for public comment that prohibit the use of non-compete agreements in the glass container
industry do not prohibit non-compete clauses for senior executives and employees involved in research and
development. See O-I Glass, Inc., File No. 211-0182, https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110182o-
iglassdraftorderappxa.pdf (Jan. 4, 2023) (Decision and Order Appendix A); Ardagh Glass Group S.A., File No. 211-
0182, https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110182ardaghdraftorderappxa.pdf (Jan. 4, 2023) (Decision and
Order Appendix A); Christine S. Wilson, Comm’r, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Dissenting Statement regarding In the
Matter of O-I Glass, Inc. and In the Matter of Ardagh Group S.A. (Jan. 4, 2023), https://www.ftc.gov/legal-
library/browse/cases-proceedings/public-statements/dissenting-statement-commissioner-christine-s-wilson-
regarding-matters-o-i-glass-inc-ardagh-group-sa.
3
Despite the importance of context and the need for fact-specific inquiries, the Commission
instead applies the approach of the newly issued Section 5 Policy Statement4F
5
to propose a near-
complete ban on the use of non-compete clauses. Pursuant to this approach, the Commission
invokes nefarious-sounding adjectives – here, “exploitive and coercive” – and replaces the
evaluation of actual or likely competitive effects with an unsubstantiated conclusion about the
tendency” for the conduct to generate negative consequences by “affecting consumers, workers
or other market participants.”5F
6
Using the approach of the Section 5 Policy Statement that enables the majority summarily to
condemn conduct it finds distasteful, the Commission today proposes a rule that prohibits
conduct that 47 state legislators have chosen to allow.6F
7
Similarly, the Commission’s proposed
rule bans conduct that courts have found to be legal,7F
8
a concern the Commission dismisses with a
claim that the Section 5 prohibition on “unfair methods of competition” extends beyond the
antitrust laws. But the majority’s conclusions and today’s proposed rule forbid conduct
previously found lawful under Section 5 of the FTC Act. Specifically, applying FTC Act Section
5, the Seventh Circuit found that “[r]estrictive [non-compete] clauses . . . are legal unless they
are unreasonable as to time or geographic scope[.]”8F
9
In other words, the Seventh Circuit found
that a fact-specific inquiry is required under Section 5.
The NPRM announced today conflicts not only with the Seventh Circuit’s holding, but also with
several hundred years of precedent. With all due respect to the majority, I am dubious that three
unelected technocrats9F
10
have somehow hit upon the right way to think about non-competes, and
that all the preceding legal minds to examine this issue have gotten it wrong. The current
rulemaking record does not convince me otherwise.
5
Fed. Trade Comm’n, Policy Statement Regarding the Scope of Unfair Methods of Competition Under Section 5 of
the Federal Trade Commission Act (Nov. 10, 2022),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/p221202sec5enforcementpolicystatement_002.pdf.
6
Id. at 9.
7
NPRM Part II.C.1. Further, the NPRM explains “[s]tates have been particularly active in restricting non-compete
clauses in recent years.” Id. The Commission’s rulemaking will end states’ varying approaches to address non-
compete agreements. The Commission’s preemption of states’ approaches is premature to the extent that the
Commission admits that it does not know where to draw lines regarding the treatment of non-compete provisions
(i.e., the Commission seeks comments on alternatives to the proposed ban based on earnings levels, job
classifications, or presumptions). The Commission ignores the advice of Justice Brandeis and instead proposes to
end states’ experimentation to determine the optimal treatment of non-compete clauses. See New State Ice Co. v.
Liebmann, 285 U.S. 262, 311 (1932) (“To stay experimentation in things social and economic is a grave
responsibility. Denial of the right to experiment may be fraught with serious consequences to the nation. It is one of
the happy incidents of the federal system that a single courageous state may, if its citizens choose, serve as a
laboratory; and try novel social and economic experiments without risk to the rest of the country.”).
8
See United States v. Empire Gas Corp., 537 F.2d 296, 307-08 (8th Cir. 1976); Lektro-Vend Corp. v. Vendo Co.,
660 F.2d 255, 267 (7th Cir. 1981); Newburger, Loeb & Co., Inc. v. Gross, 563 F.2d 1057, 1081-83 (2d Cir. 1977);
Bradford v. New York Times Co., 501 F.2d 51, 57-59 (2d Cir. 1974).
9
Snap-On Tools Corp. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 321 F.2d 825, 837 (7th Cir. 1963).
10
This characterization is not an insult, but a fact. I, too, am an unelected technocrat.
4
I. Non-Compete Agreements the First Application of the Section 5 Policy Statement
The proposed Non-Compete Clause Rule “would provide that it is an unfair method of
competition – and therefore a violation of Section 5 – for an employer to enter into or attempt to
enter into a non-compete clause with a worker; [or] to maintain with a worker a non-compete
clause . . .”10F
11
The proposed ban on non-compete clauses is based only on alleged violations of
Section 5 of the FTC Act; it is not premised on the illegality of non-compete clauses under the
Sherman or Clayton Acts.
When the Commission issued the Policy Statement Regarding the Scope of Unfair Methods of
Competition Under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act (“Policy Statement”) in
November 2022, I warned that the approach described by the Policy Statement would enable the
Commission majority to condemn conduct it disfavors, even when that conduct repeatedly has
been found lawful.1 1F
12
I predicted that the approach to Section 5 enforcement contained in the
Policy Statement would facilitate expansive enforcement, often without requiring evidence of
anticompetitive effects. And I cautioned that subjects of investigations would not be able to
defend their conduct because procompetitive justifications would not be credited. The Non-
Compete Clause Rule NPRM provides a graphic illustration of these concerns.
A. The NPRM’s Determination that Non-Compete Clauses are Unfair
The NPRM states that there are 3 independent ways for classifying non-compete clauses as an
“unfair” method of competition.12F
13
In November, I objected to the enforcement approach
described in the Section 5 Policy Statement – specifically, permitting the Commission majority
to condemn conduct merely by selecting and assigning to disfavored conduct one or more
adjectives from a nefarious-sounding list.13F
14
Here, two of the three explanations the Commission
provides for concluding that non-compete clauses are unfair rely on invocation of the adjectives
“exploitive and coercive.14F
15
The third explanation for the illegality of non-compete clauses
demonstrates how little evidence the majority requires to conclude that conduct causes harm.
According to the NPRM, “non-compete clauses are exploitive and coercive at the time of
contracting.”15F
16
The NPRM explains that the “clauses for workers other than senior executives
11
NPRM Part I.
12
See Christine S. Wilson, Comm’r, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Dissenting Statement Regarding the “Policy Statement
Regarding the Scope of Unfair Methods of Competition Under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act”
(Nov. 10, 2022), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/P221202Section5PolicyWilsonDissentStmt.pdf.
13
NPRM Part IV.A.1.
14
See Wilson, supra note 12.
15
The Policy Statement claimed that determinations of unfairness would be based on a sliding scale. Here, the
NPRM identifies independent ways to determine that non-compete clauses are unfair; no sliding scale is applied.
16
NPRM Part IV.A.1.b The NPRM explains that this conclusion does not apply to senior executives and also seeks
comment on whether there is a broader category of highly paid or highly skilled employees for whom the conclusion
is inappropriate. Id.
5
are exploitive and coercive because they take advantage of unequal bargaining power[.]”16F
17
The
business community will be surprised to learn that “unequal bargaining power” can lead to a
conclusion that any negotiated outcome may be condemned as “exploitive and coercive,” which
then can be parlayed into a finding that the conduct violates Section 5. Indeed, this assertion is
particularly troubling not merely because it presages an approach that is literally limitless, but
also because the imbalance of bargaining power, as in this setting, arises wholly apart from any
conduct by the business.17F
18
The reader may note that the NPRM cites legal decisions to support
the assignment of adjectives. Yet, a careful reading of the courts’ discussions of the imbalance of
bargaining power between employers and employees reveals that while the imbalance may
provide a reason to scrutinize non-compete clauses, it is not used to condemn or invalidate
them.18 F
19
Remarkably, in each case cited in footnote 253 of the NPRM, the court found the non-
compete clauses to be enforceable.
Next, the NPRM finds that “non-compete clauses are exploitive and coercive at the time of the
worker’s potential departure from the employer[.]”19F
20
The NPRM reaches this conclusion
regardless of whether the clauses are enforced. This conclusion is contrary to legal precedent,
which requires enforcement of non-compete provisions before finding harm.20F
21
Finally, the NPRM finds that “non-compete clauses are restrictive conduct that negatively affects
competitive conditions.”21F
22
Although this basis for concluding that non-compete provisions are
unfair does not rely solely on the selection of an adjective, here, the NPRM demonstrates how
little evidence the majority requires before finding that conduct is unfair pursuant to the Section
5 Policy Statement.
Until yesterday, the Commission had announced no cases (and therefore had no experience and
no evidence) to conclude that non-compete clauses harm competition in labor markets. In fact,
the only litigated FTC case challenging a non-compete clause found that a non-compete
17
Id.
18
According to the NPRM, unequal bargaining power arises because employees depend on job income to pay bills,
job searches entail significant transaction costs, the prevalence of unions has declined, employers outsource firm
functions, employers have more experience negotiating because they have multiple employees, employees typically
do not hire lawyers to negotiate agreements, and employees may not focus on the terms of their contracts. Id.
19
See Alexander & Alexander, Inc. v. Danahy, 488 N.E.2d 22, 29 (Mass. App. Ct. 1986) (finding injunction to
enforce non-compete agreement proper); Diepholz v. Rutledge, 659 N.E. 989, 991 (Ill. Ct. App. 1995) (finding non-
compete agreement enforceable, but also finding no violation of terms of non-compete agreement); Palmetto
Mortuary Transp., Inc. v. Knight Sys., Inc., 818 S.E.2d 724, 731 (S.C. 2018) (finding non-compete agreement
enforceable).
20
NPRM Part IV.A.1.c. Again, the NPRM explains that this conclusion does not apply to senior executives and also
invites comments on whether there is a broader category of highly paid or highly skilled employees for whom the
conclusion is inappropriate. Id.
21
See, e.g., O’Regan v. Arbitration Forums, Inc., 121 F.3d 1060, 1065-66 (7th Cir. 1997) (“to apply antitrust laws to
restrictive employment covenants, there must be some attempted enforcement of an arguably overbroad portion of
the covenant in order for there to be a federal antitrust violation.”); LektroVend Corp. v. Vendo Co., 660 F.2d 255,
267 (7th Cir.1981) (“a section 1 violation requires proof that the defendant knowingly enforced the arguably
overbroad section of the ancillary noncompetition covenant”).
22
NPRM Part IV.A.1.a.
6
provision covering franchise dealers did not violate Section 5 of the FTC Act.22F
23
Notably, the
NPRM omits any reference to this case. The Commission has accepted settlements regarding
non-compete clauses in contracts between businesses,23 F
24
but the majority itself has distinguished
those cases from non-compete clauses in labor contracts.24F
25
And in those B2B cases, the non-
compete clauses were associated with the sale of a business, a situation that falls within the
narrow exception to the ban provided in the proposed Non-Compete Clause Rule.
Just yesterday, though, the Commission rushed out the announcement of three consent
agreements that resolve allegations that non-compete provisions constitute an unfair method of
competition.25F
26
The first consent involves security guard services, and the other two involve the
manufacturing of glass containers. These consents undoubtedly were designed to support
assertions that the FTC now has experience with non-compete agreements in employee contracts.
But even a cursory read of the complaints reveals the diaphanous nature of this “experience.”
Remarkably, none of these cases provides evidence showing the anticompetitive effects of non-
compete clauses beyond the conclusory allegations in the complaints. The complaints in the glass
container industry assert that non-compete provisions may prevent entry or expansion by
competitors, but contain no allegations regarding firms that have tried unsuccessfully to obtain
personnel with industry-specific skills and experience.26F
27
Regarding the effects on employees, the
complaints make no allegations that the non-compete clauses were enforced by respondents27F
28
and the Analysis to Aid Public Comment accompanying the consent agreements points only to
studies not tied to the glass container industry. These cases provide no evidence that the non-
compete provisions limited competition for employees with industry-specific expertise, thereby
lowering wages or impacting job quality. Similarly, in the case against Prudential Security,
23
See Snap-On Tools Corp. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 321 F.2d at 837.
24
See ARKO Corp., FTC File No. 211-0187,
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110087C4773ArkoExpressComplaint.pdf (Aug. 5, 2022); DTE
Energy Co., FTC File No. 191-0068, https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/191_0068_c-4691_dte-
enbridge_complaint.pdf. (Dec. 13, 2019).
25
See Lina M. Khan, Chair, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Joined by Rebecca Kelly Slaughter and Alvaro M. Bedoya,
Comm’rs, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Statement regarding In the Matter of ARKO Corp./Express Stop,
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110187GPMExpressKhanStatement.pdf (June 10, 2022)
(distinguishing non-compete clauses in labor contracts and effects on workers from non-compete clause in merger
agreement where both parties remain in market).
26
On December 28, 2022, the Commission voted to accept for public comment three consent agreements involving
non-compete agreements. For two of those matters, the Commission vote occurred less than a week after the
Commission received the papers. See Ardagh Glass Group S.A., File No. 211-0182,
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110182ardaghacco.pdf (Jan. 4, 2023) (Agreement Containing
Consent Order (signatures dated Dec. 21, 2022)).
27
See O-I Glass, Inc., File No. 211-0182, https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110182o-
iglasscomplaint.pdf (Jan. 4, 2023) (complaint ¶¶ 6, 8); Ardagh Glass Group S.A., File No. 211-0182,
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2110182ardaghcomplaint.pdf (Jan. 4, 2023) (complaint ¶¶ 6, 8).
28
See Wilson, Dissenting Statement regarding In the Matter of O-I Glass, Inc. and In the Matter of Ardagh Glass
Group S.A., supra note 4.
7
Inc.,28F
29
the complaint alleges that individual former employees were limited in their ability to
work for other firms in the security guard industry,29F
30
but contain no allegations that the firm’s
non-compete provisions had market effects on wages or effects in a properly defined market for
security guard services.
The NPRM also asserts FTC experience with non-compete provisions by pointing to
Commission merger consent agreements that restrict the use of non-compete agreements. The
complaints in those cases did not allege harm from non-compete clauses and the provisions in
the consent agreements were included to ensure that the buyers of divestiture assets could obtain
employees familiar with the assets and necessary for the success of the divestitures at issue.
Finally, the NPRM claims Commission experience with non-compete agreements to support the
Non-Compete Clause Rule from a Commission workshop in January 2020.30F
31
But the NPRM
fails to reflect the variety of views expressed during that workshop, including testimony that the
economic literature is “[s]till far from reaching a scientific standard for concluding [that non-
compete agreements] are bad for overall welfare . . . Also [we] don’t yet fully understand the
distribution of effects on workers . . . Welfare tradeoffs are likely context-specific, and may be
heterogeneous.”31F
32
Indeed, the NPRM ignores that testimony and instead focuses on economic literature that
purportedly demonstrates that non-compete clauses are unfair because they negatively affect
competitive conditions. But an objective review of that literature reveals a mixed bag. For
example, the first study described in the NPRM32F
33
finds that “decreasing non-compete clause
enforceability from the approximate enforceability level of the fifth-strictest state to that of the
fifth-most-lax state would increase workers’ earnings by 3-4%.” Yet, this study also finds that
these effects vary strongly across different groups of individuals. For example, the authors find
that “enforceability has little to no effect on earnings for non-college educated workers” and
instead find that enforceability primarily impacts college-educated workers. Similarly, it finds
that strict non-compete clause enforceability has very different effects for different demographic
groups: it has little to no effect on men, and much larger effects on women and Black men and
women. The NPRM interprets these differential effects as facts in favor of the Non-Compete
Clause Rule, as it would diminish race and gender wage gaps, but there is no corresponding
discussion of the Rule’s effect on the wage gap based on education. An alternative interpretation
29
Prudential Security, Inc., File No. 221-0026,
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/2210026prudentialsecuritycomplaint.pdf (Dec. 28, 2022) (consent
agreement accepted for public comment).
30
Id. (complaint at ¶¶ 23, 25).
31
Fed. Trade Comm’n, Non-Competes in the Workplace: Examining Antitrust and Consumer Protection Issues,
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/events/2020/01/non-compete clauses-workplace-examining-antitrust-consumer-
protection-issues.
32
Kurt Lavetti, Economic Welfare Aspects of Non-Compete Agreements, Remarks at the Fed. Trade Comm’n
Workshop on Non-Compete Clauses in the Workplace (Jan. 9, 2020),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/1556256/non-compete=workshop-slides.pdf.
33
Matthew S. Johnson, Kurt Lavetti, & Michael Lipsitz, The Labor Market Effects of Legal Restrictions on Worker
Mobility 2, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3455381 (2020).
8
of these findings is that the scientific literature is still muddled as to who is helped and who is
harmed by non-compete clauses, and that it would be better for the Commission to tailor a rule to
those settings where a scientific consensus exists.
Similarly, the NPRM often bases its conclusions about the effects of non-compete clauses on
limited support. For example, the NPRM contends that increased enforceability of non-compete
clauses increases consumer prices. Yet, under the current record, this conclusion is based on only
one study in healthcare markets and another study that considers the relationship between non-
compete clauses and concentration.33F
34
The NPRM does not provide a basis to conclude that
findings with respect to the market for physicians and healthcare are generalizable, instead
acknowledging that no comparable evidence exists for other markets.34F
35
Also, the study that
considers the effects of non-compete clauses on concentration does not draw conclusions about
prices; the NPRM’s conclusion that non-compete provisions lead to higher prices requires
assumptions about a relationship between concentration and prices. Moreover, the NPRM omits
studies showing that reducing the enforceability of non-compete restrictions leads to higher
prices for consumers. A study by Gurun, Stoffman, and Yonker finds that an agreement not to
enforce post-employment restrictions among financial advisory firms that were members of the
Broker Protocol led brokers to depart their firms, and consumers to follow their brokers, at high
rates. The study found, however, that clients of firms in the Broker Protocol paid higher fees and
experienced higher levels of broker misconduct.35F
36
In other words, suspending non-competes
resulted in higher prices and a decrease in the quality of service provided. These unintended
consequences illustrate the inevitably far-reaching and unintended consequences that today’s
NPRM will visit upon employees, employers, competition, and the economy.
B. The NPRM’s Treatment of Business Justifications
The NPRM explains that “the additional incentive to invest (in assets like physical capital,
human capital, or customer attraction, or in the sharing of trade secrets and confidential
commercial information) is the primary justification for use of non-compete clauses.36F
37
It acknowledges that “there is evidence that non-compete clauses increase employee training and
other forms of investment,”37F
38
and describes two studies demonstrating that increased non-
compete clause enforceability increased firm-provided training and investment.38F
39
It also
34
NPRM Part II.B.2.a.
35
NPRM Part VII.B.2.c.
36
Umit G. Gurun, Noah Stoffman, & Scott E. Yonker, Unlocking Clients: The Importance of Relationships in the
Financial Advisory Industry, 141 J. Fin. Econ. 1218 (2021)
37
NPRM Part II.B.2.e.
38
Id.
39
Evan Starr, Consider This: Training, Wages, and the Enforceability of Non-Compete Clauses, 72 I.L.R. Rev. 783,
799 (2019) (moving from mean non-compete enforceability to no non-compete clause enforceability would decrease
the number of workers receiving training by 14.7% in occupations that use non-compete clauses at a high rate);
Jessica Jeffers, The Impact of Restricting Labor Mobility on Corporate Investment and Entrepreneurship 22 (2019),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3040393 (knowledge-intensive firms invest 32% less in capital
equipment following decreases in the enforceability of non-compete clauses).
9
describes studies that examine non-compete clause use and investment.39F
40
Despite the studies, the
NPRM concludes, “the evidence that non-compete clauses benefit workers or consumers is
scant.”40F
41
In other words, the NPRM treats asymmetrically the evidence of harms (mixed
evidence given great credence) and benefits (robust evidence given no credence). These early
examples of cherry-picking evidence that conforms to the narrative provide little confidence in
the integrity of the rulemaking process or the ultimate outcome.
Implicitly, though, the NPRM credits some business justifications for non-compete provisions. It
excludes from the ban those non-compete clauses associated with the sale of a business,
implicitly acknowledging that these non-compete clauses are necessary to protect the goodwill of
the transferred business. Also, the NPRM likely credits business justifications when it seeks
comment on whether senior executives should be covered by the rule. Nonetheless, on its face,
the NPRM expressly discounts business justifications and makes no effort to distinguish and
determine circumstances where investment incentives are important.
The NPRM also discounts procompetitive business justifications by asserting that trade secret
law, non-disclosure agreements, and other mechanisms can be used to protect firm investments.
While the NPRM explains that these mechanisms may protect investments, the existing record
provides no evidence that these mechanisms are effective substitutes for non-compete
agreements.4 1F
42
The NPRM cites no instances where these mechanisms have been used effectively
in lieu of non-compete clauses, even though natural experiments exist and could be studied (e.g.,
when states have changed the enforceability of non-compete clauses). “[M]erely identifying
alternative mechanisms to solve a potential employee investment problem does not provide . . .
guidance as to which mechanism achieves the objective at the lowest social cost.”4 2F
43
Moreover,
the NPRM’s observation that firms successfully operate in states where non-compete clauses are
not enforceable is unpersuasive; the NPRM offers no meaningful cross-state comparisons and the
observation does not show that firms and competition are equally or even more successful in
those states than in states where non-compete clauses are permissible.
II. The Proposed Non-Compete Clause Rule Will Trigger Numerous And Likely Successful
Legal Challenges Regarding the Commission’s Authority to Issue the Rule
40
Matthew S. Johnson & Michael Lipsitz, Why Are Low-Wage Workers Signing Noncompete Agreements?, 57 J.
Hum. Res. 689, 700 (2022) (finding firms that use non-compete clauses in hair salon industry train employees at
11% higher rate and increase investment in particular customer-attraction device by 11%); Evan P. Starr, James J.
Prescott, & Norman D. Bishara, Noncompete Agreements in the U.S. Labor Force, 64 J. L. & Econ. 53, 53 (2021)
(finding no statistically significant impact on training and trade secrets from use of non-compete clauses, but unable
to examine other types of investments).
41
NPRM Part IV.B.3.
42
There is a limited literature regarding the efficacy of trade secret protection and non-disclosure agreements. See
Jie Gong & I.P.L. Png, Trade Secrets Law and Inventory Efficiency: Empirical Evidence from U.S. Manufacturing,
https://ssrn.com/abstract=2102304 (July 8, 2012) (investigating effects of operational know-how information
spillovers under various levels of enforcement of trade secret law).
43
Camila Ringeling, Joshua D. Wright, et. al, Noncompete Clauses Used in Employment Contracts, Comment of the
Global Antitrust Institute 6 (Feb. 7, 2020), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3534374.
10
This section describes the numerous, and meritorious, legal challenges that undoubtedly will be
launched against the Non-Compete Clause Rule. Defending these challenges will entail lengthy
litigation that will consume substantial staff resources. I anticipate that the Rule will not
withstand these challenges, so the Commission majority essentially is directing staff to embark
on a demanding and futile effort. In the face of finite and scarce resources, this NPRM is hardly
the best use of FTC bandwidth.
There are numerous paths for opponents to challenge the Commission’s authority to promulgate
the Non-Compete Clause Rule. First, I question whether the FTC Act provides authority for
competition rulemaking. The NPRM states that the Commission proposes the Non-Compete
Clause Rule pursuant to Sections 5 and 6(g) of the FTC Act. Section 6(g) of the FTC Act
authorizes the Commission to “make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the
provisions of the subchapter” where Section 6(g) otherwise provides that the Commission may
“from time to time classify corporations.”43F
44
Section 6(g) was believed to provide authority only
for the Commission to adopt the Commission’s procedural rules. For decades, consistent with the
statements in the FTC Act’s legislative history, Commission leadership testified before Congress
that the Commission lacked substantive competition rulemaking authority.44F
45
44
15 U.S.C. § 46(g.). Section 6 of the FTC Act provides
§46. Additional powers of Commission
The Commission shall also have power . . .
(g) Classification of corporations; regulations
From time to time classify corporations and (except as provided in section 57a(a)(2) of this title)
to make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the provisions of this subchapter.
45
See Nat’l Petroleum Ref’rs Ass’n v. FTC, 482 F.2d 672, 696 nn. 38, 39 (D.C. Cir. 1973). See also Noah Joshua
Phillips, Against Antitrust Regulation, American Enterprise Institute Report 3, https://www.aei.org/research-
products/report/against-antitrust-regulation/ (Oct. 13, 2022) (“[T]he Conference Committee [considering legislation
that created the Federal Trade Commission] was between two bills, neither of which contemplated substantive
rulemaking. . . . The legislative history does not demonstrate congressional intent to give the FTC substantive
rulemaking power: The House considered and rejected it, the Senate never proposed it, and neither the Conference
Committee’s report nor the final debates mentioned it.”); 51 Cong. Rec. 12916 (1914), reprinted in T
HE
LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS AND RELATED STATUTES 4368 (Earl W. Kintner ed.,
1982) statement of Sen. Cummins) (“[I]f we were to attempt to go further in this act and to give the commission the
authority to prescribe a code of rules governing the conduct of the business men of this country for the future, we
would clash with the principle that we can not confer upon the commission in that respect legislative authority; but
we have not made any such attempt as that, and no one proposes any attempt of that sort.”); id. at 14932, reprinted in
T
HE LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS AND RELATED STATUTES 4732 (Earl W. Kintner ed.,
1982) (statement of Rep. Covington) (“The Federal trade commission will have no power to prescribe the methods
of competition to be used in the future. In issuing orders it will not be exercising power of a legislative nature . . .
The function of the Federal trade commission will be to determine whether an existing method of competition is
unfair, and, it is finds it to be unfair, to order the discontinuance of its use. In doing this it will exercise power of a
judicial nature.”); id. at 13317, reprinted in T
HE LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS AND
RELATED STATUTES 4675 (Earl W. Kintner ed., 1982) (statement of Sen Walsh) (“We are not going to give to the
trade commission the general power to regulate and prescribe rules under which the business of this country shall in
the future be conducted; we propose simply to give it the power to denounce as unlawful a particular practice that is
pursued by that business.”).
11
Ignoring this history, the Commission embarked on a substantive rulemaking binge in the 1960s
and 1970s.45F
46
The vast majority of these substantive rules pertained to consumer protection
issues. Only one substantive rule was grounded solely in competition;46F
47
that rule was not
enforced and subsequently was withdrawn.47F
48
Another substantive rule was grounded in both
competition and consumer protection principles, and prompted a federal court challenge. There,
the D.C. Circuit in 1973 held in National Petroleum Refiners48F
49
that the FTC did have the power
to promulgate substantive rules.
Two years later, however, Congress enacted the Magnuson-Moss Act,49F
50
which required
substantive consumer protection rules to be promulgated with heightened procedural safeguards
under a new Section 18 of the FTC Act. Notably, the Magnuson-Moss Act expressly excluded
rulemaking for unfair methods of competition from Section 18. FTC Chairman Miles Kirkpatrick
(1970-73) explained that it was not clear whether Congress in the Magnuson-Moss Act sought to
clarify existing rulemaking authority or to grant substantive rulemaking authority to the FTC for
the first time.50F
51
If the latter, then the FTC only has substantive consumer protection rulemaking
power, and lacks the authority to engage in substantive competition rulemaking. This uncertainty
about the language of the statute will be a starting point for challenges of the Non-Compete
Clause Rule.
Second, the Commission’s authority for the Rule likely will be challenged under the major
questions doctrine, which the Supreme Court recently applied in West Virginia v. EPA.51F
52
Under
the major questions doctrine, “where a statute . . . confers authority upon an administrative
agency,” a court asks “whether Congress in fact meant to confer the power the agency has
asserted.”52F
53
The Supreme Court explained in West Virginia v. EPA that an agency’s exercise of
statutory authority involved a major question where the “history and the breadth of the authority
that the agency has asserted, and the economic and political significance of that assertion,
provide a reason to hesitate before concluding that Congress meant to confer such authority.”53F
54
Challengers will ask a court to determine whether today’s NPRM constitutes a major question.
Using Justice Gorsuch’s concurrence as a guide, agency action will trigger the application of the
major questions doctrine if the agency claims, among other things, the power to (1) resolve a
46
See TIMOTHY J. MURIS & HOWARD BEALES, III, THE LIMITS OF UNFAIRNESS UNDER THE FEDERAL TRADE
COMMISSION ACT 13 (1991).
47
FTC Men’s and Boy’s Tailored Clothing Rule, 16 C.F.R. § 412 (1968).
48
Notice of Rule Repeal, 59 Fed. Reg. 8527 (1994).
49
Nat’l Petroleum Ref’rs Ass’n v. FTC, 482 F.2d 672 (D.C. Cir. 1973).
50
Magnuson-Moss Warranty Federal Trade Commission Improvement Act, Pub. L. No. 93-637, 88 Stat. 2183
(1975).
51
See Miles W. Kirkpatrick, FTC Rulemaking in Historical Perspective 48 Antitrust L.J. 1561, 1561 (1979) (“One
of the most important aspects of the Magnuson-Moss Act was its granting, or confirmation, depending upon your
reading of the law at that time, of the FTC’s rulemaking powers.”).
52
West Virginia v. EPA, 142 S. Ct. 2587 (2022).
53
Id. at 2608.
54
Id.
12
matter of great political significance, (2) regulate a significant portion of the American economy,
or (3) intrude in an area that is the particular domain of state law.54F
55
First, the regulation of non-
compete clauses is a question of political significance; Congress has considered and rejected bills
significantly limiting or banning non-competes on numerous occasions,55F
56
a strong indication that
the Commission is trying to “work around” the legislative process to resolve a question of
political significance.56F
57
Second, the Rule proposes to regulate a significant portion of the
American economy through a ban on non-competes. According to the NPRM, the “Commission
estimates that approximately one in five American workersor approximately 30 million
workers – is bound by a non-compete clause.57F
58
Thus, the Non-Compete Clause Rule
indisputably will negate millions of private contractual agreements and impact
employer/employee relationships in a wide variety of industries across the United States. Third,
regulation of non-compete agreements has been the particular domain of state law. As the NPRM
explains, 47 states permit non-competes in some capacity, while three states have chosen to
prohibit them entirely, and state legislatures have been active in this area recently.58F
59
If a court were to conclude that the Non-Compete Clause Rule is a major question, the FTC
would be required to identify clear Congressional authorization to impose a regulation banning
non-compete clauses. Yet, as discussed above, that clear authorization is unavailable. The
language in Section 6(b) is far from clear, and largely discusses the Commission’s classification
of corporations. I do not believe that Congress gave the FTC authority to enact substantive rules
related to any provision of the FTC Act using this “oblique” and unclear language. In addition,
the decision by Congress to omit unfair methods of competition rulemaking in the Magnuson-
Moss Act, which immediately followed the decision in National Petroleum Refiners, is
additional evidence that Congress has not clearly authorized the FTC to make competition rules
that may have significant political or economic consequences. Moreover, Congress did not
remove the known ambiguity when it enacted the FTC Improvements Act of 1980.59F
60
Third, the authority for the Non-Compete Clause Rule may be challenged under the non-
delegation doctrine. The doctrine is based on the principle that Congress cannot delegate its
legislative power to another branch of government, including independent agencies.60F
61
55
Id. at 2600-01 (Gorsuch, J. concurring).
56
Russell Beck, A Brief History of Noncompete Regulation, FAIR COMPETITION LAW (Oct. 11, 2021),
https://faircompetitionlaw.com/2021/10/11/a-brief-history-of-noncompete-regulation/.
57
West Virginia v. EPA, 142 S.Ct. at 2600 (Gorsuch, J. concurring).
58
NPRM Part II.B.1.a.
59
Id. Part II.C.1.
60
See H.R. Rep. No. 96-917, 96
th
Cong., 2d sess. 29-30 (1980), reprinted in THE LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE
FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS AND RELATED STATUTES 5862 (Earl W. Kintner ed., 1982) (conference report on FTC
Improvements Act of 1980 explaining that when adopting a restriction on standards and certification rulemaking
brought as an unfair or deceptive act or practice, conferees were not taking a position on the Commission’s authority
to issue a trade regulation rule defining ‘unfair methods of competition’ pursuant to section 6(g). “The substitute
leaves unaffected whatever authority the Commission might have under any other provision of the FTC Act to issue
rules with respect to ‘unfair methods of competition.’”).
61
Five Supreme Court justices have expressed interest in reconsidering the Court’s prior thinking on the doctrine,
which increases the risk that a challenge may be successful. See Gundy v. United States, 139 S. Ct. 2116, 2131
(2019) (Alito, J. concurring) (stating with respect to the nondelegation doctrine that “[i]f a majority of this Court
13
Since the 1920s, the Supreme Court has found that Congress has not made an improper
delegation of legislative power so long as Congress has set out “an intelligible principle to which
the person or body authorized to fix [rules] is directed to conform.”61F
62
Applying this principle in
Schechter Poultry,62F
63
the Supreme Court approved Congressional authorization for the FTC to
prohibit unfair methods of competition, relying on the Commission’s administrative enforcement
proceedings where the Commission acts as “a quasi judicial body” and that “[p]rovision was
made for formal complaint, for notice and hearing, for appropriate findings of fact supported by
adequate evidence, and for judicial review . . .”63F
64
The Court simultaneously found that
provisions of the National Industrial Recovery Act to issue “codes of fair competition” were
improper delegations of legislative power, distinguishing the impermissibly broad fair
competition codes from the FTC Act’s approach to address unfair methods of competition that
are “determined in particular instances, upon evidence, in light of particular competitive
conditions[.]”64F
65
Notably, the Commission’s proposed ban on non-compete clauses abandons the Commission’s
procedures that led the Supreme Court in Schechter Poultry to find that the Commission’s
enforcement of “unfair methods of competition” does not constitute an improper delegation of
legislative power. In addition, to the extent that the Commission’s Section 5 Policy Statement
(which provides the basis for determining that non-compete clauses are an unfair method of
competition) abandons the consumer welfare standard to pursue multiple goals, including
protecting labor, the Commission’s action more closely resembles the National Industrial
Recovery Act codes that also sought to implement multiple goals under the guise of codes of fair
competition.
IV. Comments are Encouraged
The NPRM invites public comment on many issues. I strongly encourage the submission of
comments from all interested stakeholders. After all, unlike rulemaking for consumer protection
rules under the Magnuson-Moss process, this is likely the only opportunity for public input
before the Commission issues a final rule. For this reason, it is important for commenters to
address the proposed alternatives to the near-complete ban on non-compete provisions. To the
extent that the NPRM proposes alternatives to the current proposed rule, if the Commission were
subsequently to adopt one of the alternatives, which would be a logical outgrowth of the current
were willing to reconsider the approach we have taken for the past 84 years, I would support that effort”); id. at 2131
(Gorsuch, J., dissenting, joined by Chief Justice Roberts and Justice Thomas) (expressing desire to “revisit” the
Court’s approach to the nondelegation doctrine); Paul v. United States, 140 S. Ct. 342, 342 (2019) (statement of
Kavanaugh, J, respecting the denial of certiorari); Amy Coney Barrett, Suspension and Delegation, 99 Cornell L.
Rev. 251, 318 (2014).
62
J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394, 409 (1928).
63
A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935).
64
Id. at 533.
65
Id.
14
proposed rulemaking,65F
66
there would be no further opportunity for public comment. Moreover,
the Commission believes that if it were to adopt alternatives that differentiate among categories
of workers, the various rule provisions would be severable if a court were to invalidate one
provision. Consequently, it is important for the public to address each of the alternatives
proposed in the NPRM because the comment period on the proposed rule is the only opportunity
for public input on those alternatives.
In addition to the issues for which the NPRM invites comments, I encourage stakeholders to
address the following points:
The NPRM references some academic studies regarding non-competes. What other
academic literature addresses the issues in the NPRM, including the procompetitive
justifications for non-compete provisions?
The NPRM describes papers that exploit natural experiments to estimate the effects of
enforcing non-compete clauses. While this approach ensures that the estimates are
internally valid, it reflects the causal effects of non-compete agreements only in the
contexts within which they are estimated. What should the Commission consider to
understand whether and when these estimates are externally valid? How can the
Commission know that the estimates calculated from the contexts of the literature are
representative of the contexts outside of the literature?
The NPRM draws conclusions based on “the weight of the literature,” but the literature
on the effects of non-compete agreements is limited, contains mixed results, and is
sometimes industry-specific. Which conclusions in the NPRM are supported by the
weight of the literature? Which conclusions in the NPRM contradict the weight of the
literature? Which conclusions in the NPRM require additional evidence before they can
be considered substantiated?
Where the evidence provided in the NPRM is limited, is the evidence sufficient to
support either the proposed ban on non-compete clauses or the proffered alternative
approaches to the proposed ban?
What are the benefits and drawbacks of the currently proposed ban compared to the
proposed alternative rule that would find a presumption of unlawfulness, including the
role of procompetitive justifications in rebutting a presumption?
66
See Owner-Operator Indep. Drivers Ass’n v. Fed. Motor Carrier Safety Admin., 494 F.3d 188, 210 (D.C. Cir.
2007); see also Agape Church, Inc. v. FCC, 738 F.3d 397, 412 (2013) (holding that FCC “sunset” rule was a logical
outgrowth when proposed rule gave public notice that a viewability rule was in danger of being phased out, i.e., a
sunset provision).